Saturday, April 20, 2024

Neoliberalism as Creative destruction by David Harvey

Neoliberalism
 as Creative
 Destruction
 By
 DAVID HARVEY
 Neoliberalism has become a hegemonic discourse with
 pervasive effects on ways of thought and political
 economic practices to the point where it is now part of
 the commonsense way we interpret, live in, and under
 stand the world. How did neoliberalism achieve such
 an exalted status, and what does it stand for? In this
 article, the author contends that neoliberalism is above
 all a project to restore class dominance to sectors that
 saw their fortunes threatened by the ascent of social
 democratic endeavors in the aftermath of the Second
 World War. Although neoliberalism has had limited
 effectiveness as an engine for economic growth, it has
 succeeded in channeling wealth from subordinate
 classes to dominant ones and from poorer to richer
 countries. This process has entailed the dismantling of
 institutions and narratives that promoted more egalitar
 ian distributive measures in the preceding era.
 Keywords: neoliberalism; globalization; fiscalization;
 class dominance; subordination
 Neoliberalism is a theory of political eco nomic practices proposing that human
 well-being can best be advanced by the maxi
 mization of entrepreneurial freedoms within an
 institutional framework characterized by pri
 vate property rights, individual liberty, unen
 cumbered markets, and free trade. The role of
 the state is to create and preserve an institu
 tional framework appropriate to such practices.
 The state has to be concerned, for example,
 with the quality and integrity of money. It must
 also set up military, defense, police, and juridi
 cal functions required to secure private prop
 erty rights and to support freely functioning
 markets. Furthermore, if markets do not exist
 (in areas such as education, health care, social
 security, or environmental pollution), then they
 David Harvey is Distinguished Professor in the
 Graduate Center of the City University of New York.
 He is author of several books, including A Brief History
 of Neoliberalism, The New Imperialism, Spaces of
 Hope, The Limits to Capital, and The Condition of
 Postmodernity.
 DOI: 10.1177/0002716206296780
 22 ANNALS, AAPSS, 610, March 2007
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 NEOLIBERALISM AS CREATIVE DESTRUCTION 23
 must be created, by state action if necessary. But beyond these tasks the state
 should not venture. State interventions in markets (once created) must be kept
 to a bare minimum because the state cannot possibly possess enough information
 to second-guess market signals (prices) and because powerful interests will
 inevitably distort and bias state interventions (particularly in democracies) for
 their own benefit.
 For a variety of reasons, the actual practices of neoliberalism frequently diverge
 from this template. Nevertheless, there has everywhere been an emphatic turn,
 ostensibly led by the Thatcher/Reagan revolutions in Britain and the United
 States, in political-economic practices and thinking since the 1970s. State after
 state, from the new ones that emerged from the collapse of the Soviet Union to
 old-style social democracies and welfare states such as New Zealand and Sweden,
 have embraced, sometimes voluntarily and sometimes in response to coercive
 pressures, some version of neoliberal theory and adjusted at least some of their
 policies and practices accordingly Postapartheid South Africa quickly adopted
 the neoliberal frame and even contemporary China appears to be headed in that
 direction. Furthermore, advocates of the neoliberal mindset now occupy posi
 tions of considerable influence in education (universities and many "think
 tanks"), in the media, in corporate board rooms and financial institutions, in key
 state institutions (treasury departments, central banks), and also in those inter
 national institutions such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the
 World Trade Organization (WTO) that regulate global finance and commerce.
 Neoliberalism has, in short, become hegemonic as a mode of discourse and has
 pervasive effects on ways of thought and political-economic practices to the point
 where it has become incorporated into the commonsense way we interpret, live
 in, and understand the world.
 Neoliberalization has in effect swept across the world like a vast tidal wave of
 institutional reform and discursive adjustment. While plenty of evidence shows
 its uneven geographical development, no place can claim total immunity (with
 the exception of a few states such as North Korea). Furthermore, the rules of
 engagement now established through the WTO (governing international trade)
 and by the IMF (governing international finance) instantiate neoliberalism as a
 global set of rules. All states that sign on to the WTO and the IMF (and who can
 afford not to?) agree to abide (albeit with a "grace period" to permit smooth
 adjustment) by these rules or face severe penalties.
 The creation of this neoliberal system has entailed much destruction, not only
 of prior institutional frameworks and powers (such as the supposed prior state
 sovereignty over political-economic affairs) but also of divisions of labor, social
 relations, welfare provisions, technological mixes, ways of life, attachments to the
 land, habits of the heart, ways of thought, and the like. Some assessment of the
 positives and negatives of this neoliberal revolution is called for. In what follows,
 therefore, I will sketch in some preliminary arguments as to how to both under
 stand and evaluate this transformation in the way global capitalism is working.
 This requires that we come to terms with the underlying forces, interests, and
 agents that have propelled the neoliberal revolution forward with such relentless
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 24 THE ANNALS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMY
 intensity. To turn the neoliberal rhetoric against itself, we may reasonably ask, In
 whose particular interests is it that the state take a neoliberal stance and in what
 ways have those interests used neoliberalism to benefit themselves rather than,
 as is claimed, everyone, everywhere?
 In whose particular interests is it that
 the state take a neoliberal stance, and in what
 ways have those interests used neoliberalism to
 benefit themselves rather than, as is claimed,
 everyone, everywhere?
 The "Naturalization" of Neoliberalism
 For any system of thought to become dominant, it requires the articulation of
 fundamental concepts that become so deeply embedded in commonsense under
 standings that they are taken for granted and beyond question. For this to occur,
 not any old concepts will do. A conceptual apparatus has to be constructed that
 appeals almost naturally to our intuitions and instincts, to our values and our
 desires, as well as to the possibilities that seem to inhere in the social world we
 inhabit. The founding figures of neoliberal thought took political ideals of indi
 vidual liberty and freedom as sacrosanct?as the central values of civilization.
 And in so doing they chose wisely and well, for these are indeed compelling and
 greatly appealing concepts. Such values were threatened, they argued, not only
 by fascism, dictatorships, and communism, but also by all forms of state inter
 vention that substituted collective judgments for those of individuals set free to
 choose. They then concluded that without "the diffused power and initiative
 associated with (private property and the competitive market) it is difficult to
 imagine a society in which freedom may be effectively preserved."1
 Setting aside the question of whether the final part ofthe argument necessar
 ily follows from the first, there can be no doubt that the concepts of individual
 liberty and freedom are powerful in their own right, even beyond those terrains
 where the liberal tradition has had a strong historical presence. Such ideals
 empowered the dissident movements in Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union
 before the end ofthe cold war as well as the students in Tiananmen Square. The
 student movement that swept the world in 1968?from Paris and Chicago to
 Bangkok and Mexico City?was in part animated by the quest for greater freedoms
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 NEOLIBERALISM AS CREATIVE DESTRUCTION 25
 of speech and individual choice. These ideals have proven again and again to be
 a mighty historical force for change.
 It is not surprising, therefore, that appeals to freedom and liberty surround the
 United States rhetorically at every turn and populate all manner of contemporary
 political manifestos. This has been particularly true ofthe United States in recent
 years. On the first anniversary ofthe attacks now known as 9/11, President Bush
 wrote an op-ed piece for the New York Times that extracted ideas from a U.S.
 National Defense Strategy document issued shortly thereafter. "A peaceful world
 of growing freedom," he wrote, even as his cabinet geared up to go to war with
 Iraq, "serves American long-term interests, reflects enduring American ideals
 and unites America's allies." "Humanity," he concluded, "holds in its hands the
 opportunity to offer freedom's triumph over all its age-old foes," and "the United
 States welcomes its responsibilities to lead in this great mission." Even more
 emphatically, he later proclaimed that "freedom is the Almighty's gift to every
 man and woman in this world" and "as the greatest power on earth [the United
 States has] an obligation to help the spread of freedom."2
 So when all of the other reasons for engaging in a preemptive war against Iraq
 were proven fallacious or at least wanting, the Bush administration increasingly
 appealed to the idea that the freedom conferred upon Iraq was in and of itself an
 adequate justification for the war. But what sort of freedom was envisaged here,
 since, as the cultural critic Matthew Arnold long ago thoughtfully observed,
 "Freedom is a very good horse to ride, but to ride somewhere."3 To what desti
 nation, then, were the Iraqi people expected to ride the horse of freedom so self
 lessly conferred to them by force of arms?
 The U.S. answer was spelled out on September 19, 2003, when Paul Bremer,
 head of the Coalition Provisional Authority, promulgated four orders that
 included "the full privatization of public enterprises, full ownership rights by for
 eign firms of Iraqi U.S. businesses, full repatriation of foreign profits . . . the
 opening of Iraq's banks to foreign control, national treatment for foreign compa
 nies and . . . the elimination of nearly all trade barriers."4 The orders were to
 apply to all areas ofthe economy, including public services, the media, manufac
 turing, services, transportation, finance, and construction. Only oil was exempt.
 A regressive tax system favored by conservatives called a flat tax was also insti
 tuted. The right to strike was outlawed and unions banned in key sectors. An
 Iraqi member of the Coalition Provisional Authority protested the forced impo
 sition of "free market fundamentalism," describing it as "a flawed logic that
 ignores history."5 Yet the interim Iraqi government appointed at the end of June
 2004 was accorded no power to change or write new laws?it could only confirm
 the decrees already promulgated.
 What the United States evidently sought to impose upon Iraq was a full
 fledged neoliberal state apparatus whose fundamental mission was and is to facil
 itate conditions for profitable capital accumulation for all comers, Iraqis and
 foreigners alike. The Iraqis were, in short, expected to ride their horse of free
 dom straight into the corral of neoliberalism. According to neoliberal theory,
 Bremer's decrees are both necessary and sufficient for the creation of wealth and
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 26 THE ANNALS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMY
 therefore for the improved well-being of the Iraqi people. They are the proper
 foundation for an adequate rule of law, individual liberty, and democratic gover
 nance. The insurrection that followed can in part be interpreted as Iraqi resis
 tance to being driven into the embrace of free market fundamentalism against
 their own free will.
 It is useful to recall, however, that the first great experiment with neoliberal
 state formation was Chile after Augusto Pinochet s coup almost thirty years to the
 day before Bremer's decrees were issued, on the "little September 11th" of 1973.
 The coup, against the democratically elected and leftist social democratic gov
 ernment of Salvador Allende, was strongly backed by the CIA and supported by
 U.S. Secretary of State Henry Kissinger. It violently repressed all left-of-center
 social movements and political organizations and dismantled all forms of popular
 organization, such as community health centers in poorer neighborhoods. The
 labor market was "freed" from regulatory or institutional restraints?trade union
 power, for example. But by 1973, the policies of import substitution that had for
 merly dominated in Latin American attempts at economic regeneration, and that
 had succeeded to some degree in Brazil after the military coup of 1964, had
 fallen into disrepute. With the world economy in the midst of a serious recession,
 something new was plainly called for. A group of U.S. economists known as "the
 Chicago boys," because of their attachment to the neoliberal theories of Milton
 Friedman, then teaching at the University of Chicago, were summoned to help
 reconstruct the Chilean economy They did so along free-market lines, privatiz
 ing public assets, opening up natural resources to private exploitation, and facili
 tating foreign direct investment and free trade. The right of foreign companies to
 repatriate profits from their Chilean operations was guaranteed. Export-led
 growth was favored over import substitution. The subsequent revival of the
 Chilean economy in terms of growth, capital accumulation, and high rates of
 return on foreign investments provided evidence upon which the subsequent
 turn to more open neoliberal policies in both Britain (under Thatcher) and the
 United States (under Reagan) could be modeled. Not for the first time, a brutal
 experiment in creative destruction carried out in the periphery became a model
 for the formulation of policies in the center.6
 The fact that two such obviously similar restructurings of the state apparatus
 occurred at such different times in quite different parts of the world under the
 coercive influence ofthe United States might be taken as indicative that the grim
 reach of U.S. imperial power might lie behind the rapid proliferation of neolib
 eral state forms throughout the world from the mid-1970s onward. But U.S.
 power and recklessness do not constitute the whole story. It was not the United
 States, after all, that forced Margaret Thatcher to take the neoliberal path in
 1979. And during the early 1980s, Thatcher was a far more consistent advocate
 of neoliberalism than Reagan ever proved to be. Nor was it the United States that
 forced China in 1978 to follow the path that has over time brought it closer and
 closer to the embrace of neoliberalism. It would be hard to attribute the moves
 toward neoliberalism in India and Sweden in 1992 to the imperial reach of the
 United States. The uneven geographical development of neoliberalism on the
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 NEOLIBERALISM AS CREATIVE DESTRUCTION 27
 world stage has been a very complex process entailing multiple determinations
 and not a little chaos and confusion. So why, then, did the neoliberal turn occur,
 and what were the forces compelling it onward to the point where it has now
 become a hegemonic system within global capitalism?
 Why the Neoliberal Turn?
 Toward the end of the 1960s, global capitalism was falling into disarray. A sig
 nificant recession occurred in early 1973?the first since the great slump of the
 1930s. The oil embargo and oil price hike that followed later that year in the wake
 ofthe Arab-Israeli war exacerbated critical problems. The embedded capitalism of
 the postwar period, with its heavy emphasis on an uneasy compact between capital
 and labor brokered by an interventionist state that paid great attention to the social
 (i.e., welfare programs) and individual wage, was no longer working. The Bretton
 Woods accord set up to regulate international trade and finance was finally aban
 doned in favor of floating exchange rates in 1973. That system had delivered high
 rates of growth in the advanced capitalist countries and generated some spillover
 benefits?most obviously to Japan but also unevenly across South America and to
 some other countries of South East Asia?during the "golden age" of capitalism in
 the 1950s and early 1960s. By the next decade, however, the preexisting arrange
 ments were exhausted and a new alternative was urgently needed to restart the
 process of capital accumulation.7 How and why neoliberalism emerged victorious
 as an answer to that quandary is a complex story. In retrospect, it may seem as if
 neoliberalism had been inevitable, but at the time no one really knew or under
 stood with any certainty what kind of response would work and how.
 The world stumbled toward neoliberalism through a series of gyrations and
 chaotic motions that eventually converged on the so-called "Washington Consensus"
 in the 1990s. The uneven geographical development of neoliberalism, and its
 partial and lopsided application from one country to another, testifies to its ten
 tative character and the complex ways in which political forces, historical tradi
 tions, and existing institutional arrangements all shaped why and how the process
 actually occurred on the ground.
 There is, however, one element within this transition that deserves concerted
 attention. The crisis of capital accumulation of the 1970s affected everyone
 through the combination of rising unemployment and accelerating inflation.
 Discontent was widespread, and the conjoining of labor and urban social move
 ments throughout much ofthe advanced capitalist world augured a socialist alter
 native to the social compromise between capital and labor that had grounded
 capital accumulation so successfully in the postwar period. Communist and social
 ist parties were gaining ground across much of Europe, and even in the United
 States popular forces were agitating for widespread reforms and state interven
 tions in everything ranging from environmental protection to occupational safety
 and health and consumer protection from corporate malfeasance. There was, in
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 28 THE ANNALS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMY
 this, a clear political threat to ruling classes everywhere, both in advanced capi
 talist countries, like Italy and France, and in many developing countries, like
 Mexico and Argentina.
 Beyond political changes, the economic threat to the position of ruling classes
 was now becoming palpable. One condition of the postwar settlement in almost
 all countries was to restrain the economic power of the upper classes and for
 labor to be accorded a much larger share of the economic pie. In the United
 States, for example, the share of the national income taken by the top 1 percent
 of earners fell from a prewar high of 16 percent to less than 8 percent by the end
 ofthe Second World War and stayed close to that level for nearly three decades.
 While growth was strong such restraints seemed not to matter, but when growth
 collapsed in the 1970s, even as real interest rates went negative and dividends
 and profits shrunk, ruling classes felt threatened. They had to move decisively if
 they were to protect their power from political and economic annihilation.
 The coup d'etat in Chile and the military takeover in Argentina, both
 fomented and led internally by ruling elites with U.S. support, provided one kind
 of solution. But the Chilean experiment with neoliberalism demonstrated that
 the benefits of revived capital accumulation were highly skewed. The country
 and its ruling elites along with foreign investors did well enough while the peo
 ple in general fared poorly. This has been such a persistent effect of neoliberal
 policies over time as to be regarded a structural component of the whole project.
 Dumenil and Levy have gone so far as to argue that neoliberalism was from the
 very beginning an endeavor to restore class power to the richest strata in the pop
 ulation. They showed how from the mid-1980s onwards, the share of the top
 1 percent of income earners in the United States soared rapidly to reach 15 percent
 by the end of the century. Other data show that the top 0.1 percent of income
 earners increased their share of the national income from 2 percent in 1978 to
 more than 6 percent by 1999. Yet another measure shows that the ratio of the
 median compensation of workers to the salaries of chief executive officers
 increased from just over thirty to one in 1970 to more than four hundred to one
 by 2000. Almost certainly, with the Bush administration's tax cuts now taking
 effect, the concentration of income and of wealth in the upper echelons of soci
 ety is continuing apace.8
 And the United States is not alone in this: the top 1 percent of income earners
 in Britain doubled their share of the national income from 6.5 percent to 13 per
 cent over the past twenty years. When we look further afield, we see extraordinary
 concentrations of wealth and power within a small oligarchy after the application of
 neoliberal shock therapy in Russia and a staggering surge in income inequalities
 and wealth in China as it adopts neoliberal practices. While there are exceptions to
 this trend?several East and Southeast Asian countries have contained income inequal
 ities within modest bounds, as have France and the Scandinavian countries?the
 evidence suggests that the neoliberal turn is in some way and to some degree asso
 ciated with attempts to restore or reconstruct upper-class power.
 We can, therefore, examine the history of neoliberalism either as a Utopian
 project providing a theoretical template for the reorganization of international
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 NEOLIBERALISM AS CREATIVE DESTRUCTION 29
 capitalism or as a political scheme aimed at reestablishing the conditions for cap
 ital accumulation and the restoration of class power. In what follows, I shall argue
 that the last of these objectives has dominated. Neoliberalism has not proven
 effective at revitalizing global capital accumulation, but it has succeeded in
 restoring class power. As a consequence, the theoretical utopianism ofthe neolib
 eral argument has worked more as a system of justification and legitimization.
 The principles of neoliberalism are quickly abandoned whenever they conflict
 with this class project.
 Neoliberalism has not proven effective at
 revitalizing gfobal capital accumulation, but it
 has succeeded in restoring class power
 Toward the Restoration of Class Power
 If there were movements to restore class power within global capitalism, then
 how were they enacted and by whom? The answer to that question in countries
 such as Chile and Argentina was simple: a swift, brutal, and self-assured military
 coup backed by the upper classes and the subsequent fierce repression of all soli
 darities created within the labor and urban social movements that had so threat
 ened their power. Elsewhere, as in Britain and Mexico in 1976, it took the gentle
 prodding of a not yet fiercely neoliberal International Monetary Fund to push
 countries toward practices?although by no means policy commitment?to cut
 back on social expenditures and welfare programs to reestablish fiscal probity. In
 Britain, of course, Margaret Thatcher later took up the neoliberal cudgel with a
 vengeance in 1979 and wielded it to great effect, even though she never fully over
 came opposition within her own party and could never effectively challenge such
 centerpieces of the welfare state as the National Health Service. Interestingly, it
 was only in 2004 that the Labour Government dared to introduce a fee structure
 into higher education. The process of neoliberalization has been halting, geo
 graphically uneven, and heavily influenced by class structures and other social
 forces moving for or against its central propositions within particular state forma
 tions and even within particular sectors, for example, health or education.9
 It is informative to look more closely at how the process unfolded in the
 United States, since this case was pivotal as an influence on other and more
 recent transformations. Various threads of power intertwined to create a transi
 tion that culminated in the mid-1990s with the takeover of Congress by the
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 30 THE ANNALS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMY
 Republican Party. That feat represented in fact a neoliberal "Contract with
 America" as a program for domestic action. Before that dramatic denouement,
 however, many steps were taken, each building upon and reinforcing the other.
 To begin with, by 1970 or so, there was a growing sense among the U.S. upper
 classes that the antibusiness and anti-imperialist climate that had emerged
 toward the end of the 1960s had gone too far. In a celebrated memo, Lewis
 Powell (about to be elevated to the Supreme Court by Richard Nixon) urged the
 American Chamber of Commerce in 1971 to mount a collective campaign to
 demonstrate that what was good for business was good for America. Shortly
 thereafter, a shadowy but influential Business Round Table was formed that still
 exists and plays a significant strategic role in Republican Party politics. Corporate
 political action committees, legalized under the post-Watergate campaign
 finance laws of 1974, proliferated like wildfire. With their activities protected
 under the First Amendment as a form of free speech in a 1976 Supreme Court
 decision, the systematic capture of the Republican Party as a class instrument of
 collective (rather than particular or individual) corporate and financial power
 began. But the Republican Party needed a popular base, and that proved more
 problematic to achieve. The incorporation of leaders of the Christian right,
 depicted as a moral majority, together with the Business Round Table provided
 the solution to that problem. A large segment of a disaffected, insecure, and
 largely white working class was persuaded to vote consistently against its own
 material interests on cultural (antiliberal, antiblack, antifeminist and antigay),
 nationalist and religious grounds. By the mid-1990s, the Republican Party had
 lost almost all of its liberal elements and become a homogeneous right-wing
 machine connecting the financial resources of large corporate capital with a pop
 ulist base, the Moral Majority, that was particularly strong in the U.S. South.10
 The second element in the U.S. transition concerned fiscal discipline. The
 recession of 1973 to 1975 diminished tax revenues at all levels at a time of rising
 demand for social expenditures. Deficits emerged everywhere as a key problem.
 Something had to be done about the fiscal crisis of the state; the restoration of
 monetary discipline was essential. That conviction empowered financial institu
 tions that controlled the lines of credit to government. In 1975, they refused to
 roll over New York's debt and forced that city to the edge of bankruptcy. A pow
 erful cabal of bankers joined together with the state to tighten control over the
 city. This meant curbing the aspirations of municipal unions, layoffs in public
 employment, wage freezes, cutbacks in social provision (education, public health,
 and transport services), and the imposition of user fees (tuition was introduced in
 the CUNY university system for the first time). The bailout entailed the con
 struction of new institutions that had first rights to city tax revenues in order to
 pay off bond holders: whatever was left went into the city budget for essential ser
 vices. The final indignity was a requirement that municipal unions invest their
 pension funds in city bonds. This ensured that unions moderate their demands to
 avoid the danger of losing their pension funds through city bankruptcy.
 Such actions amounted to a coup d'etat by financial institutions against the
 democratically elected government of New York City, and they were every bit as
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 NEOLIBERALISM AS CREATIVE DESTRUCTION 31
 effective as the military overtaking that had earlier occurred in Chile. Much of
 the city's social infrastructure was destroyed, and the physical foundations (e.g.,
 the transit system) deteriorated markedly for lack of investment or even mainte
 nance. The management of New York's fiscal crisis paved the way for neoliberal
 practices both domestically under Ronald Reagan and internationally through
 the International Monetary Fund throughout the 1980s. It established a princi
 ple that, in the event of a conflict between the integrity of financial institutions
 and bondholders on one hand and the well-being of the citizens on the other, the
 former would be given preference. It hammered home the view that the role of
 government was to create a good business climate rather than look to the needs
 and well-being of the population at large. Fiscal redistributions to benefit the
 upper classes resulted in the midst of a general fiscal crisis.
 Whether all the agents involved in producing this compromise in New York
 understood it at the time as a tactic for the restoration of upper-class power is an
 open question. The need to maintain fiscal discipline is a matter of deep concern
 in its own right and does not have to lead to the restitution of class dominance. It
 is unlikely, therefore, that Felix Rohatyn, the key merchant banker who brokered
 the deal between the city, the state, and the financial institutions, had the rein
 statement of class power in mind. But this objective probably was very much in
 the thoughts of the investment bankers. It was almost certainly the aim of
 then-Secretary ofthe Treasury William Simon who, having watched the progress
 of events in Chile with approval, refused to give aid to New York and openly
 stated that he wanted that city to suffer so badly that no other city in the nation
 would ever dare take on similar social obligations again.11
 The third element in the U.S. transition entailed an ideological assault upon the
 media and upon educational institutions. Independent "think tanks" financed by
 wealthy individuals and corporate donors proliferated?the Heritage Foundation
 in the lead?to prepare an ideological onslaught aimed at persuading the public
 ofthe commonsense character of neoliberal propositions. A flood of policy papers
 and proposals and a veritable army of well-paid hired lieutenants trained to pro
 mote neoliberal ideas coupled with the corporate acquisition of media channels
 effectively transformed the discursive climate in the United States by the mid
 1980s. The project to "get government off the backs ofthe people" and to shrink
 government to the point where it could be "drowned in a bathtub" was loudly pro
 claimed. With respect to this, the promoters ofthe new gospel found a ready audi
 ence in that wing of the 1968 movement whose goal was greater individual liberty
 and freedom from state power and the manipulations of monopoly capital. The
 libertarian argument for neoliberalism proved a powerful force for change. To the
 degree that capitalism reorganized to both open a space for individual entrepre
 neurship and switch its efforts to satisfy innumerable niche markets, particularly
 those defined by sexual liberation, that were spawned out of an increasingly indi
 vidualized consumerism, so it could match words with deeds.
 This carrot of individualized entrepreneurship and consumerism was backed
 by the big stick wielded by the state and financial institutions against that other
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 32 THE ANNALS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMY
 wing of the 1968 movement whose members had sought social justice through
 collective negotiation and social solidarities. Reagan's destruction ofthe air traf
 fic controllers (PATCO) in 1980 and Margaret Thatcher's defeat of the British
 miners in 1984 were crucial moments in the global turn toward neoliberalism.
 The assault upon institutions, such as trade unions and welfare rights organiza
 tions, that sought to protect and further working-class interests was as broad as it
 was deep. The savage cutbacks in social expenditures and the welfare state, and
 the passing of all responsibility for their well-being to individuals and their
 families proceeded apace. But these practices did not and could not stop at
 national borders. After 1980, the United States, now firmly committed to neolib
 eralization and clearly backed by Britain, sought, through a mix of leadership,
 persuasion?the economics departments of U.S. research universities played a
 major role in training many of the economists from around the world in neolib
 eral principles?and coercion to export neoliberalization far and wide. The purge
 of Keynesian economists and their replacement by neoliberal monetarists in the
 International Monetary Fund in 1982 transformed the U.S.-dominated IMF into
 a prime agent of neoliberalization through its structural adjustment programs vis
 ited upon any state (and there were many in the 1980s and 1990s) that required
 its help with debt repayments. The Washington Consensus that was forged in the
 1990s and the negotiating rules set up under the World Trade Organization in
 1998 confirmed the global turn toward neoliberal practices.12
 The new international compact also depended upon the reanimation and recon
 figuration ofthe U.S. imperial tradition. That tradition had been forged in Central
 America in the 1920s, as a form of domination without colonies. Independent
 republics could be kept under the thumb of the United States and effectively act,
 in the best of cases, as proxies for U.S. interests through the support of strongmen?
 like Somoza in Nicaragua, the Shah in Iran, and Pinochet in Chile?and a coterie
 of followers backed by military assistance and financial aid. Covert aid was available
 to promote the rise to power of such leaders, but by the 1970s it became clear that
 something else was needed: the opening of markets, of new spaces for investment,
 and clear fields where financial powers could operate securely. This entailed a
 much closer integration of the global economy with a well-defined financial archi
 tecture. The creation of new institutional practices, such as those set out by the
 IMF and the WTO, provided convenient vehicles through which financial and
 market power could be exercised. The model required collaboration among the top
 capitalist powers and the Group of Seven (G7), bringing Europe and Japan into
 alignment with the United States to shape the global financial and trading system
 in ways that effectively forced all other nations to submit. "Rogue nations," defined
 as those that failed to conform to these global rules, could then be dealt with by
 sanctions or coercive and even military force if necessary. In this way, U.S. neolib
 eral imperialist strategies were articulated through a global network of power rela
 tions, one effect of which was to permit the U.S. upper classes to exact financial
 tribute and command rents from the rest ofthe world as a means to augment their
 already hegemonic control.13
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 NEOLIBERALISM AS CREATIVE DESTRUCTION 33
 Neoliberalism as Creative Destruction
 In what ways has neoliberalization resolved the problems of flagging capital
 accumulation? Its actual record in stimulating economic growth is dismal.
 Aggregate growth rates stood at 3.5 percent or so in the 1960s and even during
 the troubled 1970s fell to only 2.4 percent. The subsequent global growth rates
 of 1.4 percent and 1.1 percent for the 1980s and 1990s, and a rate that barely
 touches 1 percent since 2000, indicate that neoliberalism has broadly failed to
 stimulate worldwide growth.14 Even if we exclude from this calculation the cata
 strophic effects of the collapse of the Russian and some Central European
 economies in the wake of the neoliberal shock therapy treatment of the 1990s,
 global economic performance from the standpoint of restoring the conditions of
 general capital accumulation has been weak.
 Despite their rhetoric about curing sick economies, neither Britain nor the
 United States achieved high economic performance in the 1980s. That decade
 belonged to Japan, the East Asian "Tigers," and West Germany as powerhouses of
 the global economy. Such countries were very successful, but their radically differ
 ent institutional arrangements make it difficult to pin their achievements on
 neoliberalism. The West German Bundesbank had taken a strong monetarist line
 (consistent with neoliberalism) for more than two decades, a fact suggesting that
 there is no necessary connection between monetarism per se and the quest to
 restore class power. In West Germany, the unions remained strong and wage levels
 stayed relatively high alongside the construction of a progressive welfare state. One
 ofthe effects of this combination was to stimulate a high rate of technological inno
 vation that kept West Germany well ahead in the field of international competition.
 Export-led production moved the country forward as a global leader.
 In Japan, independent unions were weak or nonexistent, but state investment
 in technological and organizational change and the tight relationship between
 corporations and financial institutions (an arrangement that also proved felicitous
 in West Germany) generated an astonishing export-led growth performance, very
 much at the expense of other capitalist economies such as the United Kingdom
 and the United States. Such growth as there was in the 1980s (and the aggregate
 rate of growth in the world was lower even than that of the troubled 1970s) did
 not depend, therefore, on neoliberalization. Many European states therefore
 resisted neoliberal reforms and increasingly found ways to preserve much of their
 social democratic heritage while moving, in some cases fairly successfully, toward
 the West German model. In Asia, the Japanese model implanted under authori
 tarian systems of governance in South Korea, Taiwan, and Singapore also proved
 viable and consistent with reasonable equality of distribution. It was only in the
 1990s that neoliberalization began to pay off for both the United States and
 Britain. This happened in the midst of a long-drawn-out period of deflation in
 Japan and relative stagnation in a newly unified Germany. Up for debate is
 whether the Japanese recession occurred as a simple result of competitive pres
 sures or whether it was engineered by financial agents in the United States to
 humble the Japanese economy.
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 34 THE ANNALS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMY
 So why, then, in the face of this patchy if not dismal record, have so many been
 persuaded that neoliberalization is a successful solution? Over and beyond the
 persistent stream of propaganda emanating from the neoliberal think tanks and
 suffusing the media, two material reasons stand out. First, neoliberalization has
 been accompanied by increasing volatility within global capitalism. That success
 was to materialize somewhere obscured the reality that neoliberalism was gener
 ally failing. Periodic episodes of growth interspersed with phases of creative
 destruction, usually registered as severe financial crises. Argentina was opened
 up to foreign capital and privatization in the 1990s and for several years was the
 darling of Wall Street, only to collapse into disaster as international capital with
 drew at the end of the decade. Financial collapse and social devastation was
 quickly followed by a long political crisis. Financial turmoil proliferated all over
 the developing world, and in some instances, such as Brazil and Mexico, repeated
 waves of structural adjustment and austerity led to economic paralysis.
 On the other hand, neoliberalism has been a huge success from the standpoint
 ofthe upper classes. It has either restored class position to ruling elites, as in the
 United States and Britain, or created conditions for capitalist class formation, as
 in China, India, Russia, and elsewhere. Even countries that have suffered exten
 sively from neoliberalization have seen the massive reordering of class structures
 internally. The wave of privatization that came to Mexico with the Salinas de
 Gortari administration in 1992 spawned unprecedented concentrations of wealth
 in the hands of a few people (Carlos Slim, for example, who took over the state
 telephone system and became an instant billionaire).
 With the media dominated by upper-class interests, the myth could be propa
 gated that certain sectors failed because they were not competitive enough,
 thereby setting the stage for even more neoliberal reforms. Increased social
 inequality was necessary to encourage entrepreneurial risk and innovation, and
 these, in turn, conferred competitive advantage and stimulated growth. If condi
 tions among the lower classes deteriorated, it was because they failed for personal
 and cultural reasons to enhance their own human capital through education, the
 acquisition of a protestant work ethic, and submission to work discipline and flexi
 bility. In short, problems arose because of the lack of competitive strength or
 because of personal, cultural, and political failings. In a Spencerian world, the argu
 ment went, only the fittest should and do survive. Systemic problems were masked
 under a blizzard of ideological pronouncements and a plethora of localized crises.
 If the main effect of neoliberalism has been redistributive rather than genera
 tive, then ways had to be found to transfer assets and channel wealth and income
 either from the mass of the population toward the upper classes or from vulnera
 ble to richer countries. I have elsewhere provided an account of these processes
 under the rubric oi accumulation by dispossession.15 By this, I mean the continu
 ation and proliferation of accretion practices that Marx had designated as "primitive"
 or "original" during the rise of capitalism. These include (1) the commodification
 and privatization of land and the forceful expulsion of peasant populations (as in
 Mexico and India in recent times); (2) conversion of various forms of property
 rights (common, collective, state, etc.) into exclusively private property rights;
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 NEOLIBERALISM AS CREATIVE DESTRUCTION 35
 (3) suppression of rights to the commons; (4) commodification of labor power and
 the suppression of alternative (indigenous) forms of production and consumption;
 (5) colonial, neocolonial, and imperial processes of appropriation of assets (includ
 ing natural resources); (6) monetization of exchange and taxation, particularly of
 land; (7) the slave trade (which continues, particularly in the sex industry); and (8)
 usury, the national debt, and, most devastating of all, the use of the credit system
 as radical means of primitive accumulation.
 The state, with its monopoly of violence and definitions of legality, plays a cru
 cial role in backing and promoting these processes. To this list of mechanisms, we
 may now add a raft of additional techniques, such as the extraction of rents from
 patents and intellectual property rights and the diminution or erasure of various
 forms of communal property rights?such as state pensions, paid vacations,
 access to education, and health care?won through a generation or more of social
 democratic struggles. The proposal to privatize all state pension rights (pioneered
 in Chile under Augusto Pinochet's dictatorship) is, for example, one of the cher
 ished objectives of neoliberals in the United States.
 In the cases of China and Russia, it might be reasonable to refer to recent
 events in "primitive" and "original" terms, but the practices that restored class
 power to capitalist elites in the United States and elsewhere are best described
 as an ongoing process of accumulation by dispossession that grew rapidly under
 neoliberalism. In what follows, I isolate four main elements.
 1. Privatization
 The corporatization, commodification, and privatization of hitherto public
 assets have been signal features of the neoliberal project. Its primary aim has
 been to open up new fields for capital accumulation in domains formerly
 regarded off-limits to the calculus of profitability. Public utilities of all kinds
 (water, telecommunications, transportation), social welfare provision (public
 housing, education, health care, pensions), public institutions (such as universi
 ties, research laboratories, prisons), and even warfare (as illustrated by the
 "army" of private contractors operating alongside the armed forces in Iraq) have
 all been privatized to some degree throughout the capitalist world.
 Intellectual property rights established through the so-called TRIPS (Trade
 Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights) agreement within the WTO
 defines genetic materials, seed plasmas, and all manner of other products as pri
 vate property. Rents for use can then be extracted from populations whose prac
 tices had played a crucial role in the development of such genetic materials.
 Bio-piracy is rampant, and the pillaging of the world's stockpile of genetic
 resources is well under way to the benefit of a few large pharmaceutical compa
 nies. The escalating depletion of the global environmental commons (land, air,
 water) and proliferating habitat degradations that preclude anything but capital
 intensive modes of agricultural production have likewise resulted from the
 wholesale commodification of nature in all its forms. The commodification
 (through tourism) of cultural forms, histories, and intellectual creativity entails
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 36 THE ANNALS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMY
 wholesale dispossessions (the music industry is notorious for the appropriation
 and exploitation of grassroots culture and creativity). As in the past, the power of
 the state is frequently used to force such processes through even against popular
 will. The rolling back of regulatory frameworks designed to protect labor and the
 environment from degradation has entailed the loss of rights. The reversion of
 common property rights won through years of hard class struggle (the right to a
 state pension, to welfare, to national health care) into the private domain has
 been one of the most egregious of all policies of dispossession pursued in the
 name of neoliberal orthodoxy.
 The corporatization, commodification, and
 privatization of hitherto public assets have
 been signal features ofthe neoliberal project.
 All of these processes amount to the transfer of assets from the public and
 popular realms to the private and class-privileged domains. Privatization,
 Arundhati Roy argued with respect to the Indian case, entails "the transfer of
 productive public assets from the state to private companies. Productive assets
 include natural resources: earth, forest, water, air. These are the assets that the
 state holds in trust for the people it represents. ... To snatch these away and sell
 them as stock to private companies is a process of barbaric dispossession on a
 scale that has no parallel in history."16
 2. Financialization
 The strong financial wave that set in after 1980 has been marked by its specu
 lative and predatory style. The total daily turnover of financial transactions in
 international markets that stood at $2.3 billion in 1983 had risen to $130 billion
 by 2001. This $40 trillion annual turnover in 2001 compares to the estimated
 $800 billion that would be required to support international trade and productive
 investment flows.17 Deregulation allowed the financial system to become one of
 the main centers of redistributive activity through speculation, predation, fraud,
 and thievery. Stock promotions; Ponzi schemes; structured asset destruction
 through inflation; asset stripping through mergers and acquisitions; and the pro
 motion of debt incumbency that reduced whole populations, even in the
 advanced capitalist countries, to debt peonage?to say nothing of corporate fraud
 and dispossession of assets, such as the raiding of pension funds and their decimation
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 NEOLIBERALISM AS CREATIVE DESTRUCTION 37
 by stock and corporate collapses through credit and stock manipulations?are all
 features ofthe capitalist financial system.
 The emphasis on stock values, which arose after bringing together the interests
 of owners and managers of capital through the remuneration of the latter in stock
 options, led, as we now know, to manipulations in the market that created immense
 wealth for a few at the expense ofthe many. The spectacular collapse of Enron was
 emblematic of a general process that deprived many of their livelihoods and pen
 sion rights. Beyond this, we also must look at the speculative raiding carried out by
 hedge funds and other major instruments of finance capital that formed the real
 cutting edge of accumulation by dispossession on the global stage, even as they sup
 posedly conferred the positive benefit to the capitalist class of "spreading risks."
 3. The management and manipulation of crises
 Beyond the speculative and often fraudulent froth that characterizes much of
 neoliberal financial manipulation, there lies a deeper process that entails the
 springing of the debt trap as a primary means of accumulation by dispossession.
 Crisis creation, management, and manipulation on the world stage has evolved
 into the fine art of deliberative redistribution of wealth from poor countries to
 the rich. By suddenly raising interest rates in 1979, Paul Volcker, then chairman
 ofthe U.S. Federal Reserve, raised the proportion of foreign earnings that bor
 rowing countries had to put to debt-interest payments. Forced into bankruptcy,
 countries like Mexico had to agree to structural adjustment. While proclaiming
 its role as a noble leader organizing bailouts to keep global capital accumulation
 stable and on track, the United States could also open the way to pillage the
 Mexican economy through deployment of its superior financial power under con
 ditions of local crisis. This was what the U.S. TreasuryAVall Street/IMF complex
 became expert at doing everywhere. Volker's successor, Alan Greenspan, resorted
 to similar tactics several times in the 1990s. Debt crises in individual countries,
 uncommon in the 1960s, became frequent during the 1980s and 1990s. Hardly
 any developing country remained untouched and in some cases, as in Latin
 America, such crises were frequent enough to be considered endemic. These
 debt crises were orchestrated, managed, and controlled both to rationalize the
 system and to redistribute assets during the 1980s and 1990s. Wade and Veneroso
 captured the essence of this trend when they wrote of the Asian crisis?provoked
 initially by the operation of U.S.-based hedge funds?of 1997 and 1998:
 Financial crises have always caused transfers of ownership and power to those who keep
 their own assets intact and who are in a position to create credit, and the Asian crisis is
 no exception . . . there is no doubt that Western and Japanese corporations are the big
 winners. . . . The combination of massive devaluations pushed financial liberalization,
 and IMF-facilitated recovery may even precipitate the biggest peacetime transfer of
 assets from domestic to foreign owners in the past fifty years anywhere in the world,
 dwarfing the transfers from domestic to U.S. owners in Latin America in the 1980s or in
 Mexico after 1994. One recalls the statement attributed to Andrew Mellon: "In a
 depression assets return to their rightful owners."18
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 38 THE ANNALS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMY
 The analogy to the deliberate creation of unemployment to produce a pool of
 low-wage surplus labor convenient for further accumulation is precise. Valuable
 assets are thrown out of use and lose their value. They lie fallow and dormant
 until capitalists possessed of liquidity choose to seize upon them and breathe new
 life into them. The danger, however, is that crises can spin out of control and
 become generalized, or that revolts will arise against the system that creates
 them. One ofthe prime functions of state interventions and of international insti
 tutions is to orchestrate crises and devaluations in ways that permit accumulation
 by dispossession to occur without sparking a general collapse or popular revolt.
 The structural adjustment program administered by the Wall Street/Treasury/
 IMF complex takes care of the first function. It is the job of the comprador
 neoliberal state apparatus (backed by military assistance from the imperial pow
 ers) to ensure that insurrections do not occur in whichever country has been
 raided. Yet signs of popular revolt have emerged, first with the Zapatista uprising
 in Mexico in 1994 and later in the generalized discontent that informed antiglob
 alization movements such as the one that culminated in Seattle in 1999.
 4. State redistributions
 The state, once transformed into a neoliberal set of institutions, becomes a
 prime agent of redistributive policies, reversing the flow from upper to lower
 classes that had been implemented during the preceding social democratic era.
 It does this in the first instance through privatization schemes and cutbacks in
 government expenditures meant to support the social wage. Even when privati
 zation appears as beneficial to the lower classes, the long-term effects can be neg
 ative. At first blush, for example, Thatcher's program for the privatization of
 social housing in Britain appeared as a gift to the lower classes whose members
 could now convert from rental to ownership at a relatively low cost, gain control
 over a valuable asset, and augment their wealth. But once the transfer was
 accomplished, housing speculation took over particularly in prime central loca
 tions, eventually bribing or forcing low-income populations out to the periphery
 in cities like London and turning erstwhile working-class housing estates into
 centers of intense gentrification. The loss of affordable housing in central areas
 produced homelessness for many and extraordinarily long commutes for those
 who did have low-paying service jobs. The privatization ofthe ejidos (indigenous
 common property rights in land under the Mexican constitution) in Mexico,
 which became a central component of the neoliberal program set up during the
 1990s, has had analogous effects on the Mexican peasantry, forcing many rural
 dwellers into the cities in search of employment. The Chinese state has taken a
 whole series of draconian measures through which assets have been conferred
 upon a small elite to the detriment ofthe masses.
 The neoliberal state also seeks redistributions through a variety of other means
 such as revisions in the tax code to benefit returns on investment rather than
 incomes and wages, promotion of regressive elements in the tax code (such as
 sales taxes), displacement of state expenditures and free access to all by user fees
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 NEOLIBERALISM AS CREATIVE DESTRUCTION 39
 (e.g., on higher education), and the provision of a vast array of subsidies and tax
 breaks to corporations. The welfare programs that now exist in the United States
 at federal, state, and local levels amount to a vast redirection of public moneys for
 corporate benefit (directly as in the case of subsidies to agribusiness and indi
 rectly as in the case of the military-industrial sector), in much the same way that
 the mortgage interest rate tax deduction operates in the United States as a mas
 sive subsidy to upper-income home owners and the construction of industry.
 Heightened surveillance and policing and, in the case of the United States, the
 incarceration of recalcitrant elements in the population indicate a more sinister
 role of intense social control. In developing countries, where opposition to
 neoliberalism and accumulation by dispossession can be stronger, the role of the
 neoliberal state quickly assumes that of active repression even to the point of low
 level warfare against oppositional movements (many of which can now conve
 niently be designated as terrorist to garner U.S. military assistance and support)
 such as the Zapatistas in Mexico or landless peasants in Brazil.
 In effect, reported Roy, "India's rural economy, which supports seven hundred
 million people, is being garroted. Farmers who produce too much are in distress,
 farmers who produce too little are in distress, and landless agricultural laborers
 are out of work as big estates and farms lay off their workers. They're all flocking
 to the cities in search of employment."19 In China, the estimate is that at least half
 a billion people will have to be absorbed by urbanization over the next ten years
 if rural mayhem and revolt is to be avoided. What those migrants will do in the
 cities remains unclear, though the vast physical infrastructural plans now in the
 works will go some way to absorbing the labor surpluses released by primitive
 accumulation.
 The redistributive tactics of neoliberalism are wide-ranging, sophisticated, fre
 quently masked by ideological gambits, but devastating for the dignity and social
 well-being of vulnerable populations and territories. The wave of creative
 destruction neoliberalization has visited across the globe is unparalleled in the
 history of capitalism. Understandably, it has spawned resistance and a search for
 viable alternatives.
 Alternatives
 Neoliberalism has spawned a swath of oppositional movements both within
 and outside of its compass, many of which are radically different from the worker
 based movements that dominated before 1980.1 say many but not all. Traditional
 worker-based movements are by no means dead even in the advanced capitalist
 countries where they have been much weakened by the neoliberal onslaught. In
 South Korea and South Africa, vigorous labor movements arose during the 1980s,
 and in much of Latin America working-class parties are flourishing. In Indonesia,
 a putative labor movement of great potential importance is struggling to be
 heard. The potential for labor unrest in China is immense though unpredictable.
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 40 THE ANNALS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMY
 And it is not clear either that the mass of the working class in the United States,
 which has over this past generation consistently voted against its own material
 interests for reasons of cultural nationalism, religion, and opposition to multiple
 social movements, will forever stay locked into such a politics by the machina
 tions of Republicans and Democrats alike. There is no reason to rule out the
 resurgence of worker-based politics with a strongly antineoliberal agenda in
 future years.
 But struggles against accumulation by dispossession are fomenting quite dif
 ferent lines of social and political struggle. Partly because of the distinctive con
 ditions that give rise to such movements, their political orientation and modes of
 organization depart markedly from those typical in social democratic politics. The
 Zapatista rebellion, for example, did not seek to take over state power or accom
 plish a political revolution. It sought instead a more inclusive politics to work
 through the whole of civil society in an open and fluid search for alternatives that
 would consider the specific needs of different social groups and allow them to
 improve their lot. Organizationally, it tended to avoid avant-gardism and refused
 to take on the form of a political party. It preferred instead to remain a social
 movement within the state, attempting to form a political power bloc in which
 indigenous cultures would be central rather than peripheral. It sought thereby to
 accomplish something akin to a passive revolution within the territorial logic of
 state power.
 The effect of such movements has been to shift the terrain of political organi
 zation away from traditional political parties and labor organizing into a less
 focused political dynamic of social action across the whole spectrum of civil soci
 ety. But what they lost in focus they gained in relevance. They drew their
 strengths from embeddedness in the nitty-gritty of daily life and struggle but in
 so doing often found it hard to extract themselves from the local and the partic
 ular to understand the macro-politics of what neoliberal accumulation by dispos
 session was and is all about. The variety of such struggles was and is simply
 stunning. It is hard to even imagine connections between them. They were and
 are all part of a volatile mix of protest movements that swept the world and
 increasingly grabbed the headlines during and after the 1980s.20 Those move
 ments and revolts were sometimes crushed with ferocious violence, for the most
 part by state powers acting in the name of order and stability. Elsewhere they
 produced interethnic violence and civil wars as accumulation by dispossession
 produced intense social and political rivalries in a world dominated by divide and
 rule tactics on the part of capitalist forces. Client states supported militarily or in
 some instances with special forces trained by major military powers (led by the
 United States with Britain and France playing a minor role) took the lead in a sys
 tem of repressions and liquidations to ruthlessly check activist movements chal
 lenging accumulation by dispossession.
 The movements themselves have produced an abundance of ideas regarding
 alternatives. Some seek to de-link wholly or partially from the overwhelming
 powers of neoliberalism and neoconservatism. Others seek global social and envi
 ronmental justice by reform or dissolution of powerful institutions such as the
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 NEOLIBERALISM AS CREATIVE DESTRUCTION 41
 IMF, the WTO, and the World Bank. Still others emphasize a reclaiming of the
 commons, thereby signaling deep continuities with struggles of long ago as well
 as with struggles waged throughout the bitter history of colonialism and imperi
 alism. Some envisage a multitude in motion, or a movement within global civil
 society, to confront the dispersed and de-centered powers ofthe neoliberal order,
 while others more modestly look to local experiments with new production and
 consumption systems animated by different kinds of social relations and ecologi
 cal practices. There are also those who put their faith in more conventional polit
 ical party structures with the aim of gaining state power as one step toward global
 reform ofthe economic order. Many of these diverse currents now come together
 at the World Social Forum in an attempt to define their shared mission and build
 an organizational structure capable of confronting the many variants of neoliber
 alism and of neoconservatism. There is much here to admire and to inspire.21
 Though it has been effectively disguised, we
 have lived through a whole generation of
 sophisticated class struggle on the part ofthe
 upper strata to restore or, as in China and
 Russia, construct class dominance.
 But what sorts of conclusions can be derived from an analysis of the sort here
 constructed? To begin with, the whole history of the social democratic compro
 mise and the subsequent turn to neoliberalism indicates the crucial role played
 by class struggle in either checking or restoring class power. Though it has been
 effectively disguised, we have lived through a whole generation of sophisticated
 class struggle on the part of the upper strata to restore or, as in China and Russia,
 construct class dominance. This occurred in decades when many progressives
 were theoretically persuaded that class was a meaningless category and when
 those institutions from which struggle had hitherto been waged on behalf of the
 working classes were under fierce assault. The first lesson we must learn, there
 fore, is that if it looks like class struggle and acts like class struggle, then we have
 to name it for what it is. The mass ofthe population has either to resign itself to
 the historical and geographical trajectory defined by this overwhelming class
 power or respond to it in class terms.
 To put it this way is not to wax nostalgic for some lost golden age when the pro
 letariat was in motion. Nor does it necessarily mean (if it ever should have) that
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 42 THE ANNALS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMY
 we can appeal to some simple conception of the proletariat as the primary (let
 alone exclusive) agent of historical transformation. There is no proletarian field
 of Utopian Marxian fantasy to which we can call. To point to the necessity and
 inevitability of class struggle is not to say that the way class is constituted is deter
 mined or even determinable in advance. Class movements make themselves, though
 not under conditions of their own choosing. And analysis shows that those condi
 tions are currently bifurcated into movements around expanded reproduction?in
 which the exploitation of wage labor and conditions defining the social wage are
 central issues?and movements around accumulation by dispossession?in
 which everything from classic forms of primitive accumulation through practices
 destructive of cultures, histories, and environments to the depredations wrought
 by the contemporary forms of finance capital are the focus of resistance. Finding
 the organic link between these different class currents is an urgent theoretical
 and practical task. Analysis also shows that this has to occur in an historical
 geographical trajectory of capital accumulation that is based in increasing con
 nectivity across space and time but marked by deepening uneven geographical
 developments. This unevenness must be understood as something actively pro
 duced and sustained by processes of capital accumulation, no matter how impor
 tant the signs may be of residuals of past configurations set up in the cultural
 landscape and the social world.
 Analysis also points up exploitable contradictions within the neoliberal agenda.
 The gap between rhetoric (for the benefit of all) and realization (for the benefit
 of a small ruling class) increases over space and time, and social movements have
 done much to focus on that gap. The idea that the market is about fair competi
 tion is increasingly negated by the facts of extraordinary monopoly, centralization,
 and internationalization on the part of corporate and financial powers. The star
 tling increase in class and regional inequalities both within states (such as China,
 Russia, India, Mexico, and in Southern Africa) as well as internationally poses a
 serious political problem that can no longer be swept under the rug as something
 transitional on the way to a perfected neoliberal world. The neoliberal emphasis
 upon individual rights and the increasingly authoritarian use of state power to
 sustain the system become a flashpoint of contentiousness. The more neoliberal
 ism is recognized as a failed if not disingenuous and Utopian project masking the
 restoration of class power, the more it lays the basis for a resurgence of mass
 movements voicing egalitarian political demands, seeking economic justice, fair
 trade, and greater economic security and democratization.
 But it is the profoundly antidemocratic nature of neoliberalism that should
 surely be the main focus of political struggle. Institutions with enormous lever
 age, like the Federal Reserve, are outside any democratic control. Internationally,
 the lack of elementary accountability let alone democratic control over institu
 tions such as the IMF, the WTO, and the World Bank, to say nothing ofthe great
 private power of financial institutions, makes a mockery of any credible concern
 about democratization. To bring back demands for democratic governance and
 for economic, political, and cultural equality and justice is not to suggest some
 return to a golden past since the meanings in each instance have to be reinvented
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 NEOLIBERALISM AS CREATIVE DESTRUCTION 43
 to deal with contemporary conditions and potentialities. The meaning of democ
 racy in ancient Athens has little to do with the meanings we must invest it with
 today in circumstances as diverse as Sao Paulo, Johannesburg, Shanghai, Manila,
 San Francisco, Leeds, Stockholm, and Lagos. But right across the globe, from
 China, Brazil, Argentina, Taiwan, and Korea to South Africa, Iran, India, and
 Egypt, and beyond the struggling nations of Eastern Europe into the heartlands
 of contemporary capitalism, groups and social movements are rallying to reforms
 expressive of democratic values. That is a key point of many ofthe struggles now
 emerging.
 The more clearly oppositional movements recognize that their central objec
 tive must be to confront the class power that has been so effectively restored
 under neoliberalization, the more they will be likely to cohere. Tearing aside the
 neoliberal mask and exposing its seductive rhetoric, used so aptly to justify and
 legitimate the restoration of that power, has a significant role to play in contem
 porary struggles. It took neoliberals many years to set up and accomplish their
 march through the institutions of contemporary capitalism. We can expect no less
 of a struggle when pushing in the opposite direction.
 Notes
 1. See the Web site http://www.montpelerin.org/mpsabout.cfm.
 2. G. W. Bush, "Securing Freedoms Triumph," New York Times, September 11, 2002, p. A33. The
 National Security Strategy ofthe United State of America can be found on the Web site www.whitehouse.gov
 nsc/nss. See also G. W. Bush, "President Addresses the Nation in Prime Time Press Conference," April 13,
 2004, http://www.whitehouse.gov/news/releases/2004/0420040413-20.html.
 3. Matthew Arnold is cited in Robin Williams, Culture and Society, 1780-1850 (London: Chatto and
 Windus, 1958), 118.
 4. Antonia Juhasz, "Ambitions of Empire: The Bush Administration Economic Plan for Iraq (and
 Beyond)," Left Turn Magazine 12 (February/March 2004): 27-32.
 5. Thomas Crampton, "Iraqi Official Urges Caution on Imposing Free Market," New York Times,
 October 14, 2003, p. C5.
 6. Juan Gabriel Valdez, Pinochet's Economists: The Chicago School in Chile (New York: Cambridge
 University Press, 1995).
 7. Philip Armstrong, Andre Glynn, and John Harrison, Capitalism since World War II: The Making
 and Breaking ofthe Long Boom (Oxford, UK: Basil Blackwell, 1991).
 8. Gerard Dumenil and Dominique Levy, "Neoliberal Dynamics: A New Phase?" (Manuscript, 2004), 4.
 See also Task Force on Inequality and American Democracy, American Democracy in an Age of Rising
 Inequality (Washington, DC: American Political Science Association, 2004), 3.
 9. Daniel Yergin and Joseph Stanislaw, The Commanding Heights: The Battle between Government
 and Marketplace That Is Remaking the Modern World (New York: Simon & Schuster, 1998).
 10. Thomas Byrne Edsall, The New Politics of Inequality (New York: Norton, 1984); Jamie Court,
 Corporateering: How Corporate Power Steals Your Personal Freedom (New York: Tarcher Putnam, 2003);
 and Thomas Frank, What's the Matter with Kansas: How Conservatives Won the Heart of America (New
 York, Metropolitan Books, 2004).
 11. William K. Tabb, The Long Default: New York City and the Urban Fiscal Crisis (New York,
 Monthly Review Press, 1982); and Roger E. Alcaly and David Mermelstein, The Fiscal Crisis of American
 Cities (New York, Vintage, 1977).
 12. Joseph Stiglitz, Globalization and Its Discontents (New York: Norton, 2002).
 13. David Harvey, The New Imperialism (Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2003).
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
 44 THE ANNALS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMY
 14. World Commission on the Social Dimension of Globalization, A Fair Globalization: Creating
 Opportunities for All (Geneva, Switzerland: International Labor Office, 2004).
 15. Harvey, The New Imperialism, chap. 4.
 16. Arundhati Roy, Power Politics (Cambridge, MA: South End Press, 2001).
 17. Peter Dicken, Global Shift: Reshaping the Global Economic Map in the 21st Century, 4th ed.
 (New York: Guilford, 2003), chap. 13.
 18. Robert Wade and Frank Veneroso, "The Asian Crisis: The High Debt Model versus the Wall Street
 Treasury-IMF Complex," New Left Review 228 (1998): 3-23.
 19. Roy, Power Politics.
 20. Barry K. Gills, ed., Globalization and the Politics of Resistance (New York: Palgrave, 2001); Ton
 Mertes, ed., A Movement of Movements (London: Verso, 2004); Walden Bello, Deglobalization: Ideas for a
 New World Economy (London: Zed Books, 2002); Ponna Wignaraja, ed., New Social Movements in the
 South: Empowering the People (London: Zed Books, 1993); and Jeremy Brecher, Tim Costello, and Brendan
 Smith, Globalization from Below: The Power of Solidarity (Cambridge, MA: South End Press, 2000).
 21. Mertes, A Movement of Movements; and Walden Bello, Deglobalization: Ideas for a New World
 Economy (London, Zed Books, 2002).
This content downloaded from 
95.91.214.38 on Fri, 12 Apr 2024 14:52:23 +00:00 
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms